Buffl

Theorie Part 4

SA
by Sarah A.

Dynamic Pool Problem

Now consider the case of decentralized spending. Both groups have direct access to the budget and can set expenditures on “their” public good freely. 𝑏𝑏is endogenous, 𝜏 is the residual.

 

While each group benefits only from “its own” good, it also contributes to financing the other good and to repaying debt from the first period.

 

We use backward induction (Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium).

 

In 𝑡=2, debt 𝑏 and expenditures by group 𝐼 are taken as given by 𝐽. Its period2 utility is

leading to  FOC:     


The common pool problem creates two public finance problems:

  • Taking only part of the costs and distortions created by public debt into account will lead interest groups to spend too much and to build up too much debt. There is a debt bias that leads to a structural debt problem.

  • Spending is strategically front-loaded because groups hope that higher debt will induce the other group to spend less later to avoid that taxes need to increase too much.

  • Given that all groups have the same incentive, the strategy will not work and the economy ends up with too much spending overall and spending not allocated optimally over time.

  • Theoretical base for public finance rules.

  • If there are more than two groups that can decide unilaterally, each group internalizes even smaller fractions of the future cost of debt issue and spending as well as the debt problem should become worse.

  • Empirical evidence shows that budget discipline improves

  • with the extent to which spending power is centralized in the hands of the Finance Minister or Prime Minister, and

  • if the budget process entails sequential decision making. That is, the overall budget is fixed beforeexpenditure allocation is taken.

  • Spending and debt issue is positively correlated with:

    • the number of coalition partners in government

    • the number of spending ministers in government.


War of Attrition

  • Even if policymakers from different parties, representing different societal groups, can agree on the need of a particular policy change, it is often contested who should bear the (larger part of the) costs of policy adjustment.

  • If postponing the necessary policy adjustment is costly, optimal policy would be to agree on burden-sharing and immediate adjustment.

  • The party (group) with higher costs of waiting should agree to pay larger part of the burden because its incentive for immediate adjustment is higher.

  • If, however, the individual cost of waiting is private information, both groups have an incentive to outwait the other party in the hope that it will „surrender“ first and agree to pay larger share of adjustment costs.

  • Thus, asymmetric information gives rise to „war of attrition“.

 

Examples:

  • Budget needs to be stabilized, but groups fight over who should bear a larger share of the tax increase. If no adjustment takes place, inflation or debt is used to balance budget. If costs of these distortions are asymmetric, adjustment is postponed.

  • Capital and labor might be in conflict over wage increases.Which side can hold out longer if there is a strike? Income and production losses make holding out increasingly costly.

  • All groups agree on the need for additional public spending (infrastructure, schooling …) Should increase be financed by consumption tax (VAT) or a „wealth tax“?

 

Consequence of conflict is that policy adjustment is too late which creates efficiency (and income) losses.

Author

Sarah A.

Information

Last changed