Buffl

3 Human capital

FS
by Fabienne S.

General vs. firm specific human capital revisited

There are two extreme cases:

1.

2.



Consider the following example.

Suppose training costs are 5'000 Eur and increases the worker's productivity by 5'200 Eur. The worker's productivity without training is 10'000 Eur. The firm and the worker make an agreement that the firm pays for the training and the worker stays and works for the firm for the wage that would offset the costs of training.

β€”>Is this agreement renegotiation-proof?

  • General human capital raises worker productivity equally in all firms.

  • Firm-specific human capital raises productivity in a particular firm but less so, if at all, elsewhere.

β€”>Most of the times, human capital is a mixture of general and firm-specific. E.g. in the java-tax example: training 100% in Java is only 80% effective in other firms, because they may be using different Java tools.

β€”>The distinction between general and firm-specific human capital is useful in deciding to what extent firms should subsidize on-the-job training.

  • If the human capital acquired through training is general, that is, it is equally productive in all firms, training has to be paid for by the worker.

  • Why? Because doing so maximizes total welfare.

Consider the following example.

Suppose training costs are 5'000 Eur and increases the worker's productivity by 5'200 Eur. The worker's productivity without training is 10'000 Eur. The firm and the worker make an agreement that the firm pays for the training and the worker stays and works for the firm for the wage that would offset the costs of training.

β€”>Is this agreement renegotiation-proof?

  • The firm will compensate its costs of training by paying the worker up to 10'200 Eur after training.

  • However, the worker, whose value is now 15'200 Eur will get offers up to 15'200 Eur from the outside, so the firm will have to match, or lose the worker. In any case, it will lose up to 5'000 Eur by paying for the worker's training.

  • The firm can anticipate this in advance and will therefore decide not to pay for the worker's training, even though training is welfare-improving: its net benefits were 5200 βˆ’ 5000 = 200 > 0.

β€”>This is one example of the hold-up problem: one party in the negotiations invests now anticipating to receive the benefits later, but the other party is tempted to renegotiate once the investment has been made.

β€”>The most economically efficient action to take is for the worker to finance his own general human capital training and the benefit of training, 5200 βˆ’ 5000 = 200 > 0, will be realized in terms of higher wage.

  • Alternatively, employer and worker may write a contract according to which the worker must return the costs of training if he leaves before a certain date.

  • It is a common practice, but not better in terms of welfare than making the worker pay for general training, because the firm will still recover the costs of training by preventing the worker from getting his market wage for the required amount of time.

  • Can be a useful alternative when the worker is liquidity-constrained.


Who should pay for firm specific human capital training?

Let us change our example a little bit. Now, the worker's productivity after training is 15'200 Eur if he is employed with the firm and 14'400 Eur if he is employed outside.

  • If the worker has to pay the full costs of training, 5'000 Eur, the firm will have an incentive to renegotiate his salary to 14'400 Eur after training, because that's how much he will be worth outside. The worker anticipates this and will not do the training, even though training is welfare-improving.

  • Unlike in the case of general human capital, making the worker pay for specific human capital training does not lead to the highest possible welfare.

  • Assume the firm fully pays for the firm-specific training: Now, the worker will hold-up the firm by demanding a wage up to 14'400 Eur (his outside value), whereas the firm can pay up to 10'200 Eur to recoup the costs of training. β€”>Again, not the welfare-maximizing outcome.

  • Let the firm and the worker split the costs and benefits of investment in firm-specific human capital. In our example:

    • The firm must pay to the worker at least 14'400 Eur after training to keep him, so it will earn at most 800 Eur (=15'200 - 14'400).

    • So the firm can subsidize the worker's costs of training by up to 800 Eur.

    • The worker will have to pay at least 4'200 (= 5'000 - 800) for the training, which is worth paying, because he will be earning at least 4'400 more after training.

    • Other splitting schemes are possible, but every feasible scheme must divide the gains from training of 5'200 - 5'000 = 200 in some proportion between the worker and the firm.

    • For example, in the 50-50 split, the worker earns 14'400 Eur after training and 5'700 Eur before the training. His pro t =4'400 Eur (wage gain after) - 4'300 Eur (wage loss before) =100 Eur.

    • Firm's pro t = 800 Eur (net productivity gain after training) -700 Eur (subsidy for the costs of training before) = 100 Eur.

In general:

Firm-specific training results in workers earning less than they could have earned elsewhere during training, but more than their net productivity, and earning at least as much as elsewhere after training, but less than their actual productivity

Author

Fabienne S.

Information

Last changed