Buffl

4.1 Principal-Agent model: the notion of efficiency and incentives for the risk-neutral case

FS
by Fabienne S.

Incentive contract if effort is not observed

Incentive contract if effort is not observed

  • In our basic setup output β‰ˆ effort, thus there is no uncertainty. But, effort often cannot be observed. So let us allow some uncertainty in the relationship between effort and output.

  • Suppose A can choose between high and low effort, π‘’β„Ž > 𝑒𝑙 , 𝑐(π‘’β„Ž) > 𝑐(𝑒𝑙).

    P cannot observe AΒ΄s effort choice but can observe the outcome, πœ‹β„Ž π‘œπ‘Ÿ πœ‹π‘™ , where πœ‹β„Ž > πœ‹π‘™ .

β€”>Uncertainty: If A exerts πœ‹β„Ž, πœ‹π‘™ will be achieved with a probability p, while if A exerts 𝑒𝑙 , πœ‹β„Ž can still be achieved, but with a lower probability q, i.e. 𝑝 > π‘ž. Thus relationship between AΒ΄s effort and outcome is as follows:


  • Suppose, as before, A gets a fixed wage w from P. Which effort level will A prefer to exert? Given AΒ΄s effort choice, how much money will P offer to A?

  • AΒ΄s net gain under π‘’β„Ž will be lower than under 𝑒𝑙 because 𝑐(π‘’β„Ž) > 𝑐(𝑒𝑙), so A will choose 𝑒𝑙 .

  • Anticipating this, P will offer 𝑀 = 𝑀̅ + 𝑐(𝑒).

  • Is this outcome efficient? It depends. If the expected marginal benefit of effort is higher than the marginal cost.

    That is, when 𝑝 β‹… πœ‹β„Ž + (1 βˆ’ 𝑝)πœ‹π‘™ βˆ’ (π‘ž β‹… πœ‹β„Ž + (1 βˆ’ π‘ž)πœ‹π‘™) > 𝑐(π‘’β„Ž) βˆ’ 𝑐(𝑒𝑙).

then the low wage-low effort contract is inefficient, because it prevents the realization of the highest possible net gain to A+P.


Incentives based on outcomes

Incentives based on outcomes

Suppose the high-effort outcome is efficient and P offers A the wage π‘β„Ž if the outcome is πœ‹β„Ž and 𝑏𝑙 if the outcome is πœ‹π‘™ , π‘β„Ž > 𝑏𝑙 as an incentive to exert 𝒆𝒉 rather than 𝒆𝒍 . Will this work?

β€”>Yes, under following conditions:

  1. Incentive constraint (IC):

    A must prefer π‘’β„Ž to 𝑒𝑙 , i.e.



  1. Participation constraint (PC):

    A must prefer to work for P rather than get the reservation wage outside, i.e.


  1. Limited liability constraints:

    wages must be nonnegative, i.e.



  • P will choose the values of 𝑏𝑙 , π‘β„Ž that maximize PΒ΄s profit and satisfy all the constraints, i.e. choose the lowest possible π‘β„Ž, 𝑏𝑙 that still satisfy AΒ΄s constraints.


Case 1: Both the incentive and participation constraints are binding (hold with=rather than >), and the limited liability constraints hold.

Then solving for π‘β„Ž, 𝑏𝑙 from the constraints:

This case corresponds to the fully efficient solution because A gets precisely how much it costs to exert π‘’β„Ž (no waste of money).

  • Potential problem with case 1: optimal 𝑏𝑙 may be negative, violating the limited liability constraints. This can happen when the difference 𝑝 βˆ’ π‘ž is small (lots of uncertainty in output despite high effort) and/or when extra costs of effort are high. Thus we need a case 2.


Case 2: 𝒃𝒍 = 𝟎 to satisfy the limited liability constraint. As a consequence: the participation constraint is not binding. Due 𝑏𝑙 = 0 is higher than what would satisfy the participation constraint (𝑏𝑙 < 0).

β€”>Can P compensate by reducing π‘β„Ž? No, because the incentive constraint is already binding. Thus P has to pay a rent to compensate for the difference between the optimal 𝑏𝑙 < 0 and the liability constrained 𝑏𝑙 = 0.

  • Total costs to the P under case 2:

  • R as rent, here the difference between the optimal 𝑏𝑙 < 0 and 𝑏𝑙 = 0 to satisfy PC

  • When A gets the rent, full efficiency is not achieved because the actually paid costs are higher than the level required to induce π‘’β„Ž β€”>But incentives work. Even in case 2 it is possible to motivate A to work hard, but at the price of lower efficiency.


Price rate incentive scheme

Price rate incentive scheme

It is one of the simplest incentive schemes. The setup is as follows:

  • Output produced by A. 𝑦 = 𝑒 + 𝑧, where e is effort and z is zero-mean random noise.

  • Costs of effort: 𝑐(𝑒) = 𝑒 2/2𝑐 where c is constant.

  • Wages paid P: a fixed wage s and a fraction r of every unit of output produced by A, that is 𝑀 = 𝑠 + π‘Ÿ β‹… 𝑦

  • AΒ΄s participation constraint: 𝐸(𝑀) βˆ’ 𝑐(𝑒) β‰₯ 𝑀̅

  • We still assume A is risk-neutral.


AgentΒ΄s optimal action given the incentive scheme parameters:

β€”>Higher rate means higher optimal effort. Lower c (that is, greater costs of effort) means lower optimal effort.


What is P`s optimal choice of incentives for A given AΒ΄s optimal effort choice: e*= π‘Ÿ β‹… 𝑐? P anticipates e* in deciding on the parameters of the piece rate incentive scheme, s and r.


subject to AΒ΄s participation constraint:


Substituting into maximization function gives


  • r*=1 implies that P should give ALL output to A to maximize profit.

  • Only if r*=1, A will exert the maximum effort 𝑒* = π‘Ÿ β‹… 𝑐 = 𝑐

  • AΒ΄s net expected income is


This is just enough to keep A on the participation constraint.

  • PΒ΄s profit at r*=1 is

That is, P will only hire A if PΒ΄s profit is nonnegative, implying

  • So, under the optimal piece rate incentive contract between P and A, A gets all the output (r* = 1) and pays to P (e* = c). We can also say that A β€œrents" the job from P.

    β€”>Examples of such working arrangements exist (e.g. taxi drivers, franchise owners) but are exceedingly rare.


Is the optimal piece rate contract efficient?

  • Following the efficiency criterion we search for e that maximize output under given resources, or maximize possible difference between the total output and total costs.

  • That is, the efficient piece rate incentive contract is found from

𝐹𝑂𝐢: 𝑒* = 𝑐 just like the optimal effort under the contract between P and A when r *= 1.

β€”>So, the piece rate contract between P and A presented earlier is an efficient contract.


Author

Fabienne S.

Information

Last changed